Previous Page



  Kayseri. They talked of living in urban comfort, and continuing to farm
their land by contracting and commuting. Another successful migrant had
opened a wholesale grocery business in Kayseri, using a younger brother
still resident in the village as partner. Several bought urban plots or houses
or flats and eventually moved into them, perhaps retaining a village home
for the summer months and farming some land by contract or
sharecropping or renting. In several cases where a man has several sons,
they will set up separate households but still co-operate closely
economically in enterprises outside the village. Or they may quarrel and go
their own ways.

Migrant Households

  The villages have exported a large number of households. Very
  roughly, I estimate that if we reckon, as the villagers themselves usually
do, patrilineally, then each 1950-52 household is represented now by
almost three households. I estimate, pending full analysis, that about a half
of the households descended from the 1950-52 households are now in
towns. For S village, most of them work in construction, from one rich
contractor, and another six or seven smaller contractors, through many
comfortable subcontractors, down to housepainters who earn now little
more than unskilled labourers. There are also shopkeepers, wholesalers,
milk selling businesses, minibus and lorry operators, a sewer pipe
manufacturer, and a German trained doctor practising in Hamburg. Many
of the urban children are now achieving professional level educations.
There are also casualties. There are some alcoholics and compulsive
gamblers, at least one disastrously so. Some of the urban born children are
unskilled unemployed, or low paid workers in the private sector, renting
poor homes and thus joining the urban poor. Interestingly, I have a strong
impression that E village not only contributes more educated migrants, but
also more households to the 'proletariat' - those with nothing to sell but
their labour, and not much skill at that.

  In other words, people who themselves or whose parents lived in a
  poor village, with close and intimate if often hostile and certainly unequal
relations, now span positions in the national urban hierarchy from a few
rich middle class down to a few very poor. All of them are strongly aware
of their village of origin, and most of them maintain relations with it, and
their village kin, and with their kin and fellow villagers in towns. Yet they
are now a heterogeneous network, and certainly do not seem to constitute a
working

  - 10

  class, still less a 'proletariat'. Partly, because of this heterogeneity, partly
because my analysis is incomplete, I do not here elaborate on the complex



 



  issues all this raises.

  Demographically, my provisional figures for S village show the
  average household size in the village in 1986 as 5.74 (6.0 in 1950, 6.4 in
1971), and in the towns as 4.25. The number of multiple households (those
housing more than one married couple) in the village was one in four,
whereas in the town it was one in twelve. At first sight, this fits the almost
universal sociological cliche that urbanisation and industrialisation cause a
change from the 'extended family' to the 'nuclear' family. Certainly there
are major changes in domestic structures, and in the way kinship works
and the uses to which it is put. But these changes are complex. In the short
run, some of the statistical change is related to the typical age of migrant
household heads and the fact that the bulk of the urban households have
moved out within the last twenty years.9 In the longer run, we have to
distinguish changes imposed by the constraints of the housing and labour
markets from changes in norms and images of family life and kinship
obligations.

Social Relations: The Villages

  I use this wide heading to enable me to make only a few selected
  points about the social consequences of the vastly increased prosperity in
the villages.

  Government initiatives, sometimes solicited, have provided a number
  of new amenities; schools, roads, electricity, piped water, irrigation in E
village, access to medical services, village telephones. Private initiatives
have brought buses, travelling shops and weekly markets, a huge increase
in domestic carpet weaving. Higher incomes have provided adequate diets,
decent clothes, far more domestic heating, more, better and larger houses,
far more and far more showy furnishings and domestic appliances,l°
especially televisions and refrigerators; and a whole range of other
commodities and baubles - spectacles, detergents, toys, footballs,
cosmetics, nicnacs, gadgets. The poor are fewer and less desperate than
their counterparts of 1950, though the general level of hope and aspiration
may make their poverty more conspicuous and more galling. In fact, the
poor are almost all not 'structurally ' poor, but individual victims of ill
health, misfortune or handicap.

  9 Gilleard and Gurkan (1986) show that towns have less than their share of
the old.
  10 Gilsenan (1982) pp.l85-6 with striking insight contrasts the
  austere traditional guest room with the bourgeois salon, and links it
to changes in domestic space and furnishings for rich and middle
peasants.



 




  - ll



  Two negative and polemical points. First, exploitation. Neither within
  the villages, nor between more successful and less successful migrants is
there any increase of exploitation. There is no tendency to concentrate land
holdings, and indeed the landless and unemployed are less exploited by
powerful fellow villagers, who not long ago could and sometimes did use
violence; more sons, more guns. Second, dependence. Obviously, the
villages are now far more 'dependent.' They never were independent; but
now they are closely integrated into the national economy, and directly
dependent on national and international labour markets. Economic policies
control the profitability of agriculture, the opportunities for investment,
the terms of trade, the rate of inflation, the viability of the carpet
industry.( Are they in fact more vulnerable than subsistence peasants or
pastoral nomads, who have to cope independently with weather, disease,
enemies, and governments?) In return, they enjoy a much higher standard
of living, a much greater range of economic choice, and above all they and
their children are much more prone to stay alive. And many of them have
some cushion of reserve resources against calamity.

  Next, I discuss two large and difficult issues, which are related; the
  villages as social units, social entities; and inequality and hierarchy within
them. I was struck in 1950 with the self conscious unity of the villages, and
the fact that movement of men between them was rare. Most men belonged
very sharply to, and remained for life in the village of their birth. Though
about half the women changed villages at marriage, they too remained
firmly members of their village, or of their two villages.

  Obviously, regular pendular migration, and much more strikingly,
  household migration blurs this sharp frontier. Individual members develop
loyalties and ties outside the village, and later even people who reside
entirely in towns continue to regard themselves and to be regarded as
members of the village. Many of them contribute cash and labour to village
households, and many of them receive produce, and at times financial help
or capital from the village. But obviously, the degree of 'membership'
varies from case to case, with personality, circumstances, time away from
the village; and for the town born children the ties are much weaker and
even more variable. We are dealing with something not measurable.
'Membership' of the village depends partly on material commitment - land,
remittances, houses, loans, - and partly on identity, moral commitment,
and time allocations in people's social networks. Even for those who
remain



 




  Iy.

  - 12

  in the village, the 'meaning' of belonging to it changes. In 1950, the village
was the main arena for success, power, achievement. Now people see a
very much wider and more complex world of competition and success.
How much the village matters varies with the individual and with her or
his circumstances.

  Secondly, the village hierarchy. In 1950, opportunities to accumulate
  resources were extremely limited. Those who owned land, and had sons
and animals were at the top. Those with little land, little domestic labour
and fighting power, and few or no animals were not in position to acquire
them, except gradually by good fortune, hard work, and sharp judgement
over a long period. (Stirling 1965pp. 13446). Urban earnings, and
especially foreign earnings, altered this stability. By and large, those with
both material resources, and with sophistication and social networks, are
likely to do best. But success in the new ways of accumulation is only
loosely related to previous positions in the village. One set of brothers
from a very poor father, an old man still living austerely in the old 1950
house, were all prosperous contractors and subcontractors in 1986. Such a
continuing series of changes in what was a fairly stable social order
complicates relations of inequality in the village. Instead of an agreed
hierarchy of force and ownership, the new hierarchy is far less
homogeneous or consensual, depending on a display of consumer symbols
rather than on the unspoken, agreed reality of village power. (Gilsenan
1982 p.186).

  One final point about social relations. The villages, by sending out
  labour migrants, take on a new organisational role. They become
colonisers of the towns, centres of a web of relations from Europe to Saudi
Arabia. The village now has three kinds of members. First, it has its
residents, whose daily work is concerned with with the day to day
maintenance and survival of the people (cooking, mothering, house work),
with the land and animals, with village services, or with carpet weaving.
Second, it has, as formal but absent residents, workers who work outside
it, but spend their vacations in and their earnings on the village; they
belong to village households as household heads, or as sons and brothers.
Thirdly, there are households of village people in Kayseri, Adana,
Antalya, Ankara and so on; and in Europe. These do not normally
contribute money, though many do; but they do visit, they often use the
village or migrant fellow villagers to find spouses for their young, and
they turn to the village at life crises and in troubles and disasters.



Next Page