Previous Page




  the "traditional social structure of the Ottoman Empire" as amply portrayed and
emphasized by Dr. Stirling. Differences of identification and cross-identification
with family, tribe, village community, urban center, sect, class, and racial extraction
have been in operation in this part of the world since the dawn of human history.
They are still strong forces to be reckoned with, as each national unit in the region
strives to achieve integrated and stable societal organization.

Yet we would be cherishing a distorted and misleading picture of the situation,
should we fail to see the underlying forces of unity and cohesion. These, in my
view, were mainly responsible for the continuance of a working social order over
the centuries and for the persistence of cultural identity against tremendous forces of
change. These unifying forces are likely to emerge stronger and more dominant in
the future, as Middle East society adjusts to new forms or structures. I am talking
about tribal organization, which has been a continuous source of contribution to the
way of life anywhere in the region; the farming village community with its basic
institutions, firmly established and similarly organized, whether in North Africa,
Lebanon, or Iraq; certain basic values, customs, and mores shared in common by
most of these peoples; and the dominant roles of the Arabic language and the religion
of Islam.

Thus when the Ottoman Empire came to an end, these unifying forces asserted
themselves, and the prevailing social order did not shatter into scores of fragments; it
broke into only two major entities, the new Turkey and the emergent Arab world.
The subsequent division of the latter into mandates, protectorates, and semi-
independent units was only power-politics deep. It could not penetrate to the
unifying societal core, the underlying cohesive web of life.

Another feature, which Dr. Stirling implied or mentioned briefly in his discussion,
should be specially emphasized. This is the traditional cleavage between the two
major segments of Middle Eastern society, the wide gap that separates the elite
minority at the top from the large masses at the bottom. The social, economic, and
political distances between the two are great, and the means of communication
meager. Yet the two belong organically to the same social system and are integrated
within the total cultural pattern. From this reality arises a peculiar conditioning of the
process of change and national development. At the same time it poses a stubborn
dilemma for the elite—how to accelerate the desired change for development as they
see it, whereas the social center of gravity lies among the people, who lag behind on
the other side of the gap

Indications from various fields of experience have become increasingly convincing
that here is the key feature of Middle Eastern society, through which past
developments can best be understood and future trends predicted. This is not only



 




  significant as a method of approach for students of Middle Eastern culture; it is also
of paramount importance for leaders planning and implementing various technical
developments in the region.

Let me touch briefly upon a few supporting illustrations. The "model village"
approach to the improvement of living conditions among the peasants, as practised
in some of these countries, may be well designed and sound, but only so far as the
elite designers are concerned. Upon actual implementation among the rural people,
numerous problems arise because of peculiar social and economic conditions. The
result is often unbalanced change and frustrating disorganisation.

The agricultural co-operative has proved its worth in many countries (including
some in the Middle East) over the past fifty years, as a dynamic agency of
progressive change and sound development for the farming village community. But
when the elite become impatient, and go so far as to make the co-operative a legal
obligation, both the method and the objective of the desired change are unavoidably
distorted.

Mechanized farming, now widely sought in the Middle East, serves as another good
illustration of the principle we are trying to affirm. It is dynamic and can bring about
quick changes in farming and rewarding results, but only when applied at the hands
of farmers who are ready for it, under appropriate social, economic, and technical
conditions. In many cases the leaders of development in the Middle East have gone
ahead with large-scale programs of mechanization without due consideration for
these conditions. As a result, the economic returns have not been as rewarding as
expected; also undesirable changes in the social and economic organization of rural
life have arisen.

We could go on citing many other similar cases from actual experience, but space
does not permit. The evidence is convincing, however, that the process of change
and development in the Middle East is strongly conditioned by the dominant gap in
the social structure; that the elite leadership on the one side and the large majority of
the people on the other conceive of change from different assumptions and proceed
with it at vastly different rates; that this imbalance in the process is mainly
responsible for the various manifestations of disorganization and instability in the
region; and that the main answer to the problem lies in a determined effort by the
elite to bridge the gap and achieve a more integrated social system that can move
ahead progressively as a whole.

To leave the matter at this point would amount to giving a totally negative impression
of the situation. We cannot do so, for there is a promising positive aspect, although
it is not yet dominant. In each one of the Middle Eastern countries, enlightened
elements among the elite have become thoroughly aware of this fundamental



 




  problem and have taken some firm steps in the direction of bridging the gap.

Among these steps we may enumerate the following: the Rural Social Centers in
Egypt, aimed at the uplift of the village community from within, at the level of the
people; the several community development and extension programs now in
operation in several countries, in co-operation with United States and United
Nations technical assistance agencies; the truly co-operative society of Abadiyeh
village in Lebanon, developed entirely by local leadership and initiative; the planned
resettlement of rural families and communities in the irrigation scheme of the Ghab
in northern Syria, in contrast with the absentee mechanized cotton development of
the Jezirah in that country, as discussed by Dr. Stirling; the Dujailah and other land-
distribution and resettlement projects of Iraq; the national agrarian reform programs
of Turkey and Egypt and by the Shall of Iran on the royal domain; the recent
emphasis upon fundamental education under the leadership of UNESCO and the
determined trend toward universal elementary schooling.

Dr. Stirling has discussed at length the leading roles played by modern technology
and improved methods of administration in the changing Middle Eastern society. I
wish to elaborate briefly with two observations. The first is that the process of
technical change, so far, has taken place mainly on the basis of borrowing from the
outside and imposition from above. It has been, so to speak, set free to take its
course, without much consideration for its far-reaching implications and
repercussions in the living patterns of the people and the social structure. Concern
has been primarily for the immediate result wanted from the borrowed item of
technology. Beyond that, the chips have been left to fall as they would and society to
adjust belatedly the best it could.

Thus, for example, the modern industrial plant was set up but there were no plans
for the arising labor needs or anticipation of labor problems. The tractor, the
irrigation pump, and the automobile substantially increased production and income
for the tribal chief, but they helped turn him into an absentee landlord and his
kinsmen into landless sharecroppers. Piped water assured an adequate and readily
available supply for the village folk, but it did away with the traditional social
institution that had developed over the centuries around the village well. Through
efficient techniques of communication and transportation, central authorities were
better able to prevent raiding, keep peace among the tribes, and push for their
settlement, but no provisions were made for adequate substitutes to avoid physical
and moral deterioration. The modern system of higher education was set up
successfully, but it drew away promising youth from the local communities, thus
accentuating the gap in the social structure.

One may argue that all of this, and more, is part of the price any society must pay for



 




  its gain from technical advancement. This is true, but only to a certain degree. The
difference is great indeed, in the magnitude of arising problems and the degree of
disorganisation, between a society adjusting to technical change from within its own
pattern of culture, and another, like the Middle East, borrowing intensively from
abroad. In the former case, it is a matter of healthy, balanced growth, with possible
minor crises; whereas in the latter it is intensive, one-sided change, by forces alien to
the native culture, beyond the capacity of society to absorb the shock and adjust
effectively.

I wish, however, to go one step further and assert that it is not inevitable that the
process of technical change in the Middle East should always demand such a high
price in disorganization, frustration, and upheaval. Borrowing from culture to
culture can take place selectively. Adoption of modern technology can be planned to
fit the economy and other aspects of the receiving culture. Social science has
advanced sufficiently to enable us to detect tensions arising from new techniques and
provide for adequate solutions. The successful adoption of this course, however,
rests upon the assumption that there is a thorough understanding of, and respect for,
the culture, the way of life of the people. I am talking about the people of the Middle
East as they actually live today in their villages, tribal communities, and urban
centers.

My observation on public administration in the Middle East is that it has lagged
glaringly behind technical change, to the detriment of both and of society as a whole.
This is another manifestation of the preoccupation with the tangible material aspects
of development and the relative disregard of the human aspect. The underlying
erroneous assumption is that technology is sufficient unto itself, that once it is
borrowed and established, human relations will take care of themselves and the
social system will adjust to the new situation automatically. The process of change
does not function this way; stable social organization rests upon the thorough
integration of technical change with institutional change.

A few examples will show how this lag in public administration manifests itself. The
forms of civil service established in the area are similar to their counterparts in
Western countries, from which most of them have been copied. Yet they are vastly
different in content and application. There are standards for the selection of civil
servants, but actual appointment of personnel to the job submits, to one degree or
another, to the practice of nepotism. Full-time service is required from the official,
but in many cases he is underpaid and must seek an additional job to meet his needs.
The usual hierarchy of personnel is well established, and the pyramid of job
classification defines and distributes functions adequately. In practice, however,
there is so much centralization of authority that initiative is stifled and efficiency
reduced materially. The adopted technology creates new situations in human
relations and calls for new forms of organization. These require specially trained and



Next Page   Contents

Return to Papers index