Previous Page



  explosion (Stirling, 1974).  In order to earn, a farmer goes
to town and learns a new skill; he may even go to a new
country.  Even to go to town, he needs information.  When
he gets there he needs to know how to survive.  To earn, he
needs to know not only what the job requires, but who gives
jobs, how they can be persuaded to choose him; and so on.
Those who enter new skilled occupations - the building trade,
contracting, shopkeeping, manufacturing cement sewer pipes
- need to know a lot more.  Young men in the village learn
to repair tractors, operate videos, mend refrigerators, wire
houses.  All who do not, go and talk to those who do.
Everyone watches television and listens to the radio.  I was
constantly asked about Thatcher and Liverpool (football).
The State, through schools, colleges and universities, and
through the Office of Religious Affairs is pumping out vast
quantities of new knowledge and ideology.  In short, the
increase since 1950 in 'knowledge' in Turkey, in the sense of
all the bits of information and misinformation, facts, ideas,
theories, dogmas, stories, cannot be measured; but it is
certainly huge, vast; and underestimated, under-researched
and under-discussed.  Of course, everyone knows about the
need for formal knowledge, for science and technology.
What is not discussed is what I call social cognition
(Fischer,1991).  Humans seldom stop talking.  Out of this
continuous conversation is created a shared world of ideas
and beliefs built - now - round the multitude of new
experiences and new learning and new purposes which arise
from new social contexts.  All this is linked to the new
occupational structure, and to the growth of new
organisations; greatly augmented by formal education,
television in almost every home, and an active press.  But it
is also part of every social encounter in the land.  (11).
The words 'information' or 'knowledge' imply feeding
blocks of truth into a vacuum.  But this new socially shared
construction of reality is grounded in existing experience,
and existing cognitive structures.  People, as they pass it on
to others, add home-made logic, plausible connections,
misunderstandings, and that quintessential human gift,
fantasy.  This vast arena of possible ideas is flexible and
kaleidoscopic.  The people who are doing new jobs,
operating in and manipulating new organisations and social
networks, are also living in new cognitive worlds of their



 



  own shared constructions.  These constructions are of course
constantly trimmed by real - or imagined - experience.
Some ideas, new and old, take a long time to change; some
never do.  Moreover, these cognitive processes are not
homogeneous; they generate cognitive proliferation, and
open fierce arguments, even violence.  That is, in time,
people, within the cultural unity derived from, imposed by
the nation state, become, more or less fortuitously, more and
more culturally distinct.  (l2)

A digression.  Social cognition seems to me highly relevant
to the 'Islamic Revival', and to the academic and political
discussion about it.  Islam provides most Turks with (among
other things) a cosmos, a guarantee, an ultimate Legitimation
of social order, morality and purpose.  But people's
cognitive worlds are in complex flux, from science and
Darwinian evolution in schools, and a secular, elected
government which controls religion and pays all imams, to
an international world, seen mainly as hostile, dominated by
Europe, the USA, Japan and the multinationals.  Of course,
not all Turks live in the same Islamic universe in the first
place (Tapper, 1991; Shankland, Chapter 4).  But making
sense of their new worlds in terms of their old cosmos gives
people a whole spectrum of different constructions of reality
and of morality.  I find it consistent (notice that I am
implying causal connection) with this generalising
impressionistic description that some of these new
constructions proclaim new fundamentalist certainties,
which, though seen as grounded in the old unchangeable
revelation, in fact provide a new social and political
programme to cope with the new situations and new threats.

(vii) Causal Complexity
Each of these five headings is shorthand for a whole set of
further points; and they are not independent.  Isolating topics
for research is essential.  But it is both difficult, because of
the seamless tangles which are social reality; and dangerous,
because the simplifying essential to comprehensibility is
likely also to mislead.  This brings me back to the theme of
complexity.  Many models, for example, the argument for a
distinguishable set of 'paths of transformation' (Keyder,
Chapter 12; Aksit, Chapter 13) are not wrong.  They are too



 



  simple.  We need to work out more complex models; much
more complex.  I know that I am not able to do so.  Others
may be more confident.

Values Again
All these changes cause new, sometimes intense suffering,
and a host of perceived injustices and grievances.  So did
similar changes in Europe and the USA; and have already
(with worse to come?) in former socialist countries now
attempting a market economy and democratic polities.  For
Turkey, the suffering apart, there are those who lament the
Mercedes culture of the idle rich, the nationalisation of local
'folk' music, the transformation of the five days of village
weddings into an evening in a hired hall with the bride in a
white European dress, the arrival of western symphony
orchestras, and nouvelle vogue films in Turkish elite
'culture'.  Not to mention discussions of the
'peripheralisation' of the Turkish economy; its subordination
to western based multinationals, international banks, and the
interests of the G7; the 'forced' rural urban migration,
consumerism, sharp and growing inequalities, and
secularism, agnosticism and anti-secularism.  Not surprising
that some of Delaney's village informants share her
suspicions of modernism and progress (Chapter 10).  But I
do not want to reverse it all.  I would not want my best
village friend's gelin, who was saved by caesarian in the
Kayseri University hospital, to have died with her child, as
she would have in 1950.  Nor do I want people to be walking
in the snow without shoes, shivering because their supply of
cattle dung cakes has run out before the end of winter, nor
seeing their children weedy from malnutrition.

The extollents and the denouncers of modernisation, or
capitalism, are both highly selective.  How can anyone
make an overall moral judgement on all these processes of
change?  They have happened:  the results are there.  As an
anthropologist, I am part of a collective effort to understand
them.  I find the complexity incredibly difficult to analyse.
As a moral person, I have my own views and I hold that
understanding social processes is relevant both to
judgements, and to framing successful policies at all
levels.  But I also hold that understanding achieving



 



  'trust', that is, less misleading models of social processes is a
separate and morally neutral task.

Notes

1.  I first realised the startling speed of growth in the first
two decades from tables 3.2 (p.46) and 4.5 and 4.6 (pp.76-
7), in Hale 1981, based on Bulutay et al.  1974.  See also
tables 5.10 (pp.  108) and 7.2, 7.3 (pp.1323), based on DSI
1973, and more recent official sources.  See, e.g., Turkey
Economy, Aug.  1992, p.47.
2.  All school children in Turkey declare daily in unison
how fortunate they are to be Turks; to the surprise of
visiting foreign children - recent personal communication
from foreign children.
3.  'The poor are not just living off the crumbs from the rich
man's table, they are being asked to put the crumbs back',
David Bryer, Oxfam director, Observer 11 October 1992.
4.  Of course I am not claiming any demographic rigour.
My reasons for not following up the households of married
daughters, and daughters' daughters, as well as those of
married sons and sons' sons, were largely pragmatic; but also
related to the perceptions and knowledge of my largely male
informants.  The decision was taken in 1950, and
irreversible.
5.  All published numbers are calculated from economic
models.  Hard empirical evidence that unemployment is now
serious and growing rests on widespread personal
impressions.  Certainly in 1986, the greater part of the
village and migrant households which I knew had at last an
adequate income, and many were comfortable.  I knew of
very few adult men who could be called 'unemployed', on a
long term basis.  The majority worked intermittently; and
except at harvest, most men present in the village at any onc
time had little to do.  By contrast, David Shankland
commenting on this note, reponed personally a large
amount of unemployment in the Alevi village which he
studied, and among its migrants (Chapter 4)
6.  Notice that Turkish has no word for 'peasant'; koylu -
villager - is not 'peasant,' though most peasants are koylu,
and most koylu peasants.  cf.  Keyder (Chapter 12).



Next Page   Contents

Return to Papers index