Previous Page



  humans will eventually enjoy human rights, and all will be
comfortable and happy, if unequal.  Except, of course, sadly,
for the inevitable losers at the bottom (20 per cent?); the
unfortunate, the incompetent, the undeserving, the unduly
unselfish; and the individually bad, or rather, the bad who
are unsuccessful.  These are taken care of by private charity,
by public welfare, and by the police and the prisons.Radicals
- mainly (at the time of the conference) varieties of marxists
and socialists - stress the appalling and cruel inequalities of
modern capitalism, both within and between nations; the
ways that the rich and powerful, deliberately or
inadvertently, exploit the poor for their own advantage, and
prevent them from catching up(3); and, incidentally, are
destroying the planet in the process.  They advocate or used
to - an alternative road to universal happiness, based on
rational, egalitarian and selfless co-operation and equality,
organised by benign public control.  Both sides treat 'culture'
as a set of economically irrelevant pleasures and customs,
and of traditional, even 'irrational', practices and 'attitudes',
which may well inhibit progress.  They do not allow for a set
of autonomous 'cultural' factors in the social process; still
less do they see themselves, their theories, and their political
supporters as social and cultural phenomena to be analysed;
phenomena which their own theories do not explain.These
theories, like most -all - others, advocate or imply
moralities, and purposes.  People, including academics, see
opponents as lost in culpable error, even as morally 'evil'.
In spite of endless discussion of 'values' in the social sciences,
the damage they do to clear thinking still seems to me
seriously underestimated.  If my own strongly held and often
incompatible moralities confuse my own thinking, I find the
same difficulties in much that I read.

Four Convictions
These papers then confirm four long-standing convictions.
First, that the main task, and one which all of us take
seriously, is modestly to establish specific causalities; that is,
that a factor X has at least some influence on an outcome Y;
or that an outcome Y is in part a result of a factor X.  Yet
authors avoid using the word 'cause' itself, using instead an
endless variety of euphemisms.  Second, that both the 'facts'
and the causal processes about which most of us express some



 



  confidence are far more difficult to establish than most of us
admit.  Third, the central words, the major concepts, are
virtually always shifting and fuzzy.  Fourth,  we claim to
study the 'mental maps', 'models' - large scale and small
scale, culturally and personally constructed - which other
people live.  It is fashionable to stress, more than in the
recent past, that we too have such mental maps and models,
which are likewise constructed by our own cultures and
personalities.obviously true and important; implying a duty
for 'reflexivity'.But it does not follow that our work is
invalid These 'maps' are transmissible,  discussable and in
spite of losses, errors and misunderstandings, are by and
large cumulalivei they do get better as maps over time.  To
put the point differently, mankind has manifestly in the last
10,000 years, and especially in the last 200, accumulated by
logic and evidence an immense store of 'truth', of effective
maps of reality; social as well as physical.  Yet it remains
true (!) that every individual human lives, must live, in a
cognitive universe, the main outlines of which rest not on
logic, evidence and research, but on faith.  And moreover
even the myriad practical detailed maps of social reality
which describe bits of that universe for daily use also rest
more often on faith or on authority than on experience,
direct evidence and logic.  The ethnography of.these 'maps'
is both central to the changes in Turkey, and extremely
difficult to record accurately.

Comments and Conclusions
Do I myself draw any conclusions about Turkey? Yes, with
these reservations.  Six generalisations based on these
thirteen excellent articles, and on over forty years of my
own work in and on Turkey; with theoretical and, I regret,
moral overtones.  And a last comment on values.

(i) Demography
The population of Turkey, as I have said, has increased by
a factor of over 4 since 1923; and since my arrival in
1950, by 2.5; from 20 million to well over 50 million.  In S
in 1950, 600 people resided in 100 households.  In 1986,
we estimated 840 people in the village in some 143
households, and 650 people outside the village in 165
households, all descended patrilineally from those six



 



  hundred.4 These national and local increases are directly due
to falling death rates, especially among children.Two points:
this growth is both proof and the direct result of a general
rise in the standard of living.  Second, in no way could these
extra people have stayed alive without labour migration from
the villages.  Some migrants diversified and increased village
household incomes by remitting urban earnings; some
permanently removed whole households which the villages
could neither feed nor employ.  This huge increase in the
numbers of both urban cash earners, and of rural and urban
consumers, must be an integral part of any causal model of
social change.  Without remittances and departures, rural
death rates would have simply continued much as before.Was
this increase in people, with all its consequences, a good
thing or a bad thing? That is quite another - unanswerable?
question.  I would not know how to begin deciding, but it is
not my job - our job - to do so.

(ii) Economic Growth
The real average standard of living has risen sharply.  GNP
per capita increased roughly threefold, 1950 - 1986.  What I
see among the villagers and their urban descendants makes
these calculations a plausible index.  Food, clothes, heating,
housing, transport, health services, household durables and
furniture, consumption for pleasure and for display,
operating capital for farming, investments in agriculture,
real estate and businesses are all incomparably more plentiful
per person than in 1950; three times is not obviously
wrong.  Agriculture alone nowhere near accounts for the
increase.  In the plateau villages which I know, with poor
soils and a dry climate, the changes in agricultural techniques
and crops have brought increases of around 50 per cent in
production per hectare.  Tractors and other machinery have
greatly reduced the male labour required per hectare, and
thus given a large increase in agricultural productivity per
man per day.  As Morvaridi stresses, some agricultural
changes actually increase the demand for, and burden of,
some kinds of female labour, mostly unpaid; and many
women suffer directly.  But it does not follow that even their
productivity has not risen; and when household income rises,
as he says, women also get some benefit.In other parts of
Turkey, technical and crop changes, often combined with



 



  irrigation - cotton, citrus, vegetables, dairying, poultry, meat
production, and so on - have increased both production per
hectare and productivity per person, on a dramatic scale; in
some cases agricultural labour demand has actually increased
(Ak,sit, Chapter 13 and Sirman, 1988).  These increases in
turn depend on industrialisation; on tractors, fertilisers,
transport, packaging, food processing; and on markets.

The growth of the urban economy - industry and services -
has created a huge demand for this rural labour surplus.  I
now realise that till at least the late 1950’s, Turkey had in
fact a national labour shortage, greatly aggravated
undoubtedly by local and seasonal under- and un-
employment, by shortages of many much needed skills, and
by geographical maldistribution.  In hard fact, no one knows,
or has ever known, real current unemployment rates.(5).
Wallerstein (Smith and Wallerstein, 1992) has recently
classified household incomes into five sources; subsistence,
profits, wages, investment income, and transfers.  In 1950,
most household income was mainly subsistence, with some
profits, from land and animals; wages were already
important for a minority.  In 1986, all normal households
had multiple incomes, of which that from land and animals
made up on average a very.  much smaller part; in S, I
estimate less than half the total village income.Certainly, still
in 1986, some were poor, and a few very poor.  The most
common causes of poverty were illness, handicap, or
premature death.  Where a household had no land, or very
little, no adult man fit to work and earn, and no unmarried
carpet-weaving daughters, life could be very hard indeed.  In
towns, unskilled or socially unsuccessful men might earn
very little; the old might not earn at all.  But in 1986, the
handicapped apart, no one we met or heard about from the
two villages seemed to be hungry, cold or in rags.  In
1950/1, many were.  In terms of material wealth and
comfort, 1986 is, on average and for the vast majority, a
totally different world from 1950.

(iii) Inequality
Successful capitalism creates wealth; a very large amount of
it.  It does nothing whatsoever to ensure that this wealth is
'fairly', let alone equally distributed; nor that the production



Next Page   Contents

Return to Papers index