Previous Page



  of it is humane and environmentally harmless.  On the
contrary, wherever capitalism has prospered, it has led to
major concentrations of wealth and power for some,
destitution for others; and to all kinds of skulduggery,
exploitation, suffering, social disruptions and political
upheavals, not to mention ecological damage.  All
governments exercise a vast plethora of controls over market
forces in the public interest, and by and large with
considerable success.  They must and do buck the market,
and the market in turn depends on a minimal political
guarantee of order

Overall, Turkey has currently one of the largest statistical
skews between rich and poor reported in the World
Development Report (World Bank, 1986).  A few people -
most had advantages to begin with - have got very rich; most
are decidedly better off; some have remained poor; a few
have even got poorer (Paleczek, Chapter 7).  Some enjoy
excellent amenities, even in so called gecekondus; others
live and work in terrible conditions, often away from their
families for long periods.  Could such a society, with
different policies, have achieved this growth with less
inequality, disruption, and suffering? Or could it have grown
even faster? As a social scientist, I do not know; does
anyone?

(iv) Occupational Change
The population not directly dependent on agriculture went up
from around 4 million in 1950 to about 27 million in 1986,
nearly seven times (Istatistik Y1111gl, 1951, 1986).  Four-
fifths of these extra 23 million must have been the children,
children's children, or children's children's children of
peasant families.
A 'peasant'(6) household is assumed - far too simply - to
farm land and raise animals, which roughly employs all its
collective labour, and produces enough in kind and in
commodities to provide for all its collective needs.  In a
village of peasant households, the occupation of peasant is not
an identity.  A man is not what he does for a living, but the
owner of a specific house and specific land, belonging in a
specific way to a specific village.  Men, women and children
work as members of household teams.  In 1950, in S and E,



 



  direct close links with townspeople were fairly rare (cf.
Turhan, 1951, Keyder, Chapter 12).  Men who go to town,
go to earn, that is, to find a job.  In these villages, it was
often a building skill; though I do have a list of about a
hundred different occupations.  Whatever the job, the new
job holder has to develop an occupational network to get,
keep or renew it, and to make it comfortable and lucrative.
In the town a man is what he does.  People learn all kinds of
skills and find all kinds of jobs, and by doing so, they
become new 'persons' with different identities.  They now
belong, both immediately and potentially, to a much more
complex social structure, with many new kinds of social
relations; and with different futures (Schiffaucr, Chapter 5),
as most contributors in this book make clear.

It is a commonplace that villages forge bridgeheads for
finding urban jobs and urban housing.  So sometimes people
from a given area are concentrated in particular occupations,
and sometimes in particular districts in cities.  This is not by
any means universal.  S men migrants, for example, are
nearly all connected to the building industry, (most of them
are tilers), but they are residentially scattered.  The
detailed distribution of people in occupations - and also by
residence - is not decided primarily by market forces, but by
a whole set of interacting factors, among which the market is
only one.Millions of villagers are now distributed in urban
Turkey in hundreds of new and different occupations, in a
wide variety of residences and with a wide range of
education and statuses; they all live in social networks very
different from those of full-time farming villagers, and often
from each other.  They do not constitute collectively a
proletariat, still less an 'informal sector'(7).   Occupational
change is central to economic growth; and that requires
radical changes in identities, in social structure, in skill and
knowledge, and a fortiori in 'culture'.  Because virtually all
villages, and most village households, have now members
earning in towns, or former members resident in town,
village social networks and identities have also changed
dramatically (cf.  Schiffauer, Chapter 5, Abadan-Unat,
Chapter 14).  Their networks are far more dispersed  and
integrated with the national and international society, and
with Turks abroad; and far less homologous with those of



 



  fellow villagers.  Villagers' village identities reflect the
occupations, incomes, social statuses, and destinations of both
their pendular and their household migrants.

(v) Organisational Change
The co-ordinated arrangements of people in groups to get
things done are central to all activities in all societies.
Unfortunately, in social science literature, 'organisation'
often suggests modern management; and 'social
organisation', traditional kinship.  Even in small groups,
such arrangements virtually always involve some hierarchy.
Organised groups have problems; control and delegation,
legitimacy, privileges for some, internal competition,
incompetence, and the use of organisational power and
resources for private, even nefarious, purposes; larger
groups have more problems.  The most conspicuous form of
large organisation is the State itself, government - which was
after all only invented about 6,000 years ago.  My own
hunch is that the progressive invention of more and more
effective forms of co-ordinating people for an increasing
variety of social purposes is one main factor in human social
evolution.  What sets the USA, Germany and Japan at the
apex of the contemporary world is superior organisation.
Likewise, the recent manifest political and economic failure
of most of the world's socialist governments is
organisational.  The state has simply failed to run a modern
economy efficiently and benignly.  Turkey's growth.has
involved the invention, reinvention and borrowing of dozens
of new kinds of organisation; and the establishment or
expansion of thousands of new and old organisations.
Discovering and setting up effective rules, controls and
arrangements, training personnel, building up experience and
informal working practices takes decades.  Since (almost?)
all humans are primarily concerned with their personal
power and prestige, controllers and members of
organisations often put their private interests ahead of those
of the organisation (Stirling, 1968).  In all countries, 'better'
organisation is an issue.  In Turkey, from the organisation of
the government itself down to the village midwife sunning
herself in the garden of her government house, there is a vast
amount to be learned - and applied - about effectiveness,
commitment and supervision.(8).



 



  The villagers of course always knew effectively about their
own organisations; households, farming, marriages, villages,
markets, and relations with their State.(9).  But they have
also learned an enormous amount about outside organisations
of many kinds.  They learn mainly ad hoc what it is in their
interest to know, what helps them to solve the next problem.
They can only do this within the limits of their existing
knowledge, perceptions and experience; and of their own
morality.  Enriching their household, or doing favours for
kin friends and allies is a moral duty; far more important
than observing specific laws or formal rules, or pursuing the
planned purposes of other people's organisations.  By
contrast, villagers who become entrepreneurs find
themselves needing to organise and control others in new
ways, and to establish new kinds of relations with other
businessmen, professionals, and officials.  Many villagers
from S and E now act as building contractors, many run
commercial undertakings, retail and wholesale, and a few
have become manufacturers.  A large number are building
subcontractors in a given craft.  All these have to learn to
manage the internal and external relations of new
organisations unlike villages and farming households.

A great many Turks, and not only villagers, seem to assume
that if you want something from, or within, a large
organisation, then to get it, what you most need is not a
formally correct case, nor even manipulative knowledge of
the working of the system, but a personal link to someone of
power above or within the organisation who is prepared to
use that power on your behalf.  Thus personal networks,
'patron client relations', are thought to be the most crucial
factor in the daily running of organisations (Gune,s-Ayata,
1990).  This perception, which is far too simple not to be
false, closely matches the villagers' experience, assumptions
and commitment to households and friends.  Village and
migrant morality fit cosily into this national culture of
networking.  Which raises interesting, if sensitive, questions
for another occasion (10).

(vi) Cognitive Change.
Nothing struck me more forcibly when I returned to the two
villages in 1971 than what I then called the information



Next Page   Contents

Return to Papers index