Previous Page




  unacceptable, was granted from personal knowledge and for personal reasons,
and the orders to collect the necessary documents followed. The documents and
records even for many officials are not therefore instruments for ensuring
impartiality and efficiency, but arbitrary, if necessary, conditions of certain
kinds of action. No wonder official records are often inaccurate, incomplete or
out of date.

My argument so far has been as follows. The system I have called personal
morality is extremely strong in societies composed of relatively closed
communities. When a society of this kind forms part of a larger political unit,
which in theory pursues its purposes according to impersonal, impartial and
efficient procedures, the bureaucracy must in practice adapt itself to the
pressures of personal morality in the society which it is attempting to
administer, permitting favouritism, ad hoc decisions, departures from and
stretchings of the regulations, with consequential inefficiency and indifference
to the purposes of the bureaucratic institutions, which become systems of linked
positions of privilege and power.

Most pre-industrial States were concerned primarily with two objects —the
maintenance of public order, including the maintenance of the power of the
rulers, and the collections of taxes. Besides these, they had to maintain a
judicial system for the peaceful settlement of disputes and the prevention of
public defiance of rules laid down by the State or imposed by public moral
values, and a number of public services—communications, the regulation of
economic life, and more recently, public health and education. In such systems,
the bureaucracy is primarily regulatory and predatory, and is not an instrument
for social change nor for distributing State benefits. Although bureaucrats in
such societies sometimes had immense power locally, they were still
comparatively few in number and limited in their corruption by the size of the
State resources they were allowed to handle, and by the fact that even if the
illiterates could not control their official functions, their own educated
kinsmen—the landowners and merchants with whom they had tight
personalties—could and did. Moreover, so long as no one expects rapid
development, and the society functions, inefficiency is not of great importance.
Indeed, a certain degree of failure to apply rules through adaptation to local
pressures tends to preserve social stability.

What dramatically alters this situation is the attempt—almost universal in this
new world of developing territories and international aid—to use the
bureaucracy as an instrument for rapid social change through the expenditure of
vast new State resources, moving into the local society from above. In Italy, at
the same time, the bureaucracy is called upon to operate complex new schemes



 




  of State benefits; in particular, complex schemes for collecting contributions and
distributing benefits under official but semi-independent social and health
insurance societies.

From the point of people living in the society it is not the overall aim of
economic development and social justice that seems important, but the fact that a
new supply of jobs, money and benefits has suddenly become available. A
privately financed non-political organisation working for adult education,
planned a centre in a small Lucanian town. Even before they were ready to start
building, the community was riven by quarrels about who was to get work as
labourers on the building site. Similarly, when millions—miliardi in Italian
terms—are to be spent, before all the laws and plans have been worked out and
are ready for practical application, people on the spot have been scheming and
organising, not in terms of desirable changes in their society, but in terms of
their own immediate advantage —jobs, contracts, percentages.

In Italy, the influx of new resources through the Casa per il Mezzogiorno, both
directly and indirectly, broke open a relatively stable social order. People move
about as jobs became available and communications improve. Individuals seize
new opportunities with very different degrees of luck and acumen, and the
established hierarchy of social rank is upset. As a result of these changes, the
informal controls formerly exercised over the traditional bureaucrats in a more
or less static society diminish, leaving the new holders of power and privilege
much freer. Secondly, the shifting situation and the larger number of office
holders provides all kinds of new situations for the exercise of personal
pressures. Whereas formerly people knew more or less what could and what
could not be obtained and how to go about getting it, now the possibilities are
vastly increased and no one can be sure of the results of attempts to exercise
personal pressure. Many people will suffer disappointments, others will be
busy experimenting with new forms of imbroglio.

A Liberal candidate, speaking publicly before the elections of April 28th, 1963,
admitted that the Liberals operated a client-patron system in the pre-Fascist
south. But, he said, it was organised, predictable and humane, not random and
chaotic like the Democratic Christian patron-client system of to-day. If he is
right in his facts, he is wrong in his implications. The randomness is not the
fault of the Democratic Christian Party, but of the new open social situation.

Uncertainty and social mobility increase resentment. We know that closed
communities usually react with malice towards successful members, —a
prophet hath no honour,—and may on occasion succeed by gossip or witchcraft
accusations, or some other such pressure, in pushing them down again
(Colson, 1953; Gluckman, 1955.) In South Italy, this resentment takes the less



 




  effective form of accusations of imbroglio, normally ex post facto and without
evidence. Thus the fact that the society is in movement generates suspicion and
accusations which in turn probably tend to increase the actual extent of
corruption.

The particular way in which personal relationships compromise the impartiality
and efficiency of a bureaucracy vary according to the social structure of each
country. As I have said, in the paesi of south Italy until late 1940's, the local
borghesia was in an extremely strong position, partly because of its monopoly
of education and contacts with the sources of power and authority, partly
because the Fascist repression supported them, and partly because population in
relation to resources was so intense that the bottom ranks of society were
divided by competition for bread and unable to combine against their rulers. The
only path was to become a client, as servile as possible, in the hopes of being
rewarded with work or with land to rent. Fear kept people submissive, and in
this situation a paternalistic client-patron relationship flourished in which the
rulers and owners had to do very little for their supporters in order to retain their
loyalty,—in striking contrast with many much more primitive societies, where
offended followers might rebel, or simply walk out and join another chief. Thus
certain ways of thinking, certain attitudes already existed in the society on to
which developments and the welfare state imposed the vast increase of
bureaucratic activity, and helped to guide it towards a personal morality.

Political developments in post-war Italy have also been a special factor in the
development of personal relations within the bureaucracy. One party
government in any society encourages the government's supporters to intervene
in the bureaucracy partly for simple political purposes, and partly because the
successful government politicians also wish at the same time to butter their own
personal bread. Ataturk's Turkey provides an excellent example of such a
system, with close ties at every point between the party hierarchy and the
official organs of State. A recent thesis on Turkey provides a different kind of
example from the Democrat Party regime of Adnan Menderes (Szyliowicz,
1961), showing in detail the intrigues of the Democratic Party to win votes at
the local level by manipulating bureaucratic behaviour through political
pressures.

One sanction against this kind of behaviour is the existence of a well organised
opposition capable of replacing the government, and prepared to art as a
watchdog. Since the war no such opposition has existed in Italy. The
Democratic Christian Party, by far the largest on the Italian scene, is not a single
party with a clear ideology and policy, but an anti-communist Catholic
federation of opposed interests. Threatened only by the Communist Party, the



 




  D.C. set itself to fight the political battle with all the traditional weapons of the
patron-client system. Hence to the pressures from below towards a system of
personal relationships, they added an example of political clientship and
interference from above. The political success of these tactics has not been
impressive, but undoubtedly they have reinforced tendencies to corruption
already present in the social structure. Moreover, because the party was a
federation, and had been steadily forced to accept more and more political allies
to preserve its majority, it has lacked the authority to subdue private interest
groups to the interests of the State. like Fascist system of governing, though
semi-independent enti charged with carrying out major State functions has been
continued, and expanded. These enti, once created, have shown themselves
capable of joining in the intrigues round the government in the interests of their
own operations, and naturally, of the importance of their own directors, and the
safety of the jobs of their own staff.

Examples abound. Most striking of all is the body formed before fascism as a
federation of local landowner's cooperatives for buying seed and supplies and
selling products. The Federconsorzi, converted already to government
purposes, was charged by the Fascists with executing government policies for
food and agricultural products during the war, and has retained the function of
buying grain for the government, at a subsidised price, compulsorily until
1960, now in a free market. The organisation also retained its function as a
supplier to farmers. It ran stores, workshops, flour mills, olive oil presses,
made special agreements with Fiat for tractors and with the fertiliser industry,
and set up or took shares in subsidiary companies for processing and marketing
fruit, vegetables, wine and oil. It has become the fourth largest financial
concern in Italy, after Fiat, Finsider (state steel), and E.N.I. (state oil) [Rossi-
Doria, 1963]. This body shared directors with the pro-government Coltivatori
Diretti, a sort of Catholic trade union, representing small cultivators all over
Italy, which claims the allegiance of some seventy D.C. deputies elected by its
votes.

This is only one example. Italy, alone as far as I know, still in 1963 had two
bodies which sprang from U.N.R.R.A., the postwar U.N. relief organisation,
both performing jobs with State money which one might think belonged to
normal ministries. The policy continues. Among the new sixty odd State-
imposed insurance societies, one is worth a comment. In 1960, in order to
introduce a medical aid group for independent small cultivators, the government
instituted a separate Casa Mutua Coltivatori Diretti, for every province. Though
legally separate, these bodies organisationally are run by the officers of the pro-
government Coltivatori Diretti, to which all small cultivators must therefore
belong, at least medically. Naturally, insurance schemes produce large sums for
investment, and these are also under the management of government



Next Page   Contents

Return to Papers index