Previous Page




  investigation. His object is rather to ensure an acceptable and speedy settlement,
and if he fails, either side can appeal to court.(3)

Paradoxically, registration of land may even make a settlement more difficult
rather than easier. Peasants seldom register changes, whether by inheritance or
by sale, of ownership of registered land. Hence, in cases of inheritance, they
simply make their own ad hoc arrangements, which, though extra-legal, are in
practice, at least for the time being, accepted by the village. But incomplete or
disputed registration brings in the bureaucracy, as well as the courts, and may
involve reference to Ankara.

The legal situation is complicated by the fact that the ad hoc arrangements which
the villagers make among themselves are seldom a strict application of the law
of inheritance in the new code. The villagers are aware of the main provisions,
namely that sons and daughters should take equal shares of the parental land,
and that a surviving widow should take a quarter.(4) Since most men go to
great lengths to ensure that they have children to survive them, and since even
the childless often take a child from a close kinsman (5) and bring it up as their
own, it seldom happens that a man dies without children to act as his heirs.
There were no bachelors over the age of about 23 in the villages in which I
worked, and very few landowning childless couples who no longer had hopes
of having children. Land normally remains the property of the head of a
household till he dies, and his sons stay in the household and work it with him.
Thus people practically never own land before their father is dead. When the
head of a household does die, the household and its land usually remains an
economic unit for at least a few months, sometimes for years, depending on the
size of the household, the amount of land, the personal relations between the
brothers and between their wives, and so on. Very often, an ad hoc
arrangement, in theory, is temporarily made between the brothers, since their
sisters are now married, and not therefore at the time of the death of the father
living in the household land. Such an arrangement, once made, is not easy to
upset, and any attempt to do so by the sisters or their husbands will usually
mean a dispute, indeed, this is one of the commonest types of dispute.
Sometimes of course, sisters may be given a share of land at the first division—
if, for example, there is plenty of land, and a sister lives in the village so that
her marital household can make use of it. Alternatively, either at the time or
later, the claims of sisters may be settled by a money payment. Quite often,
however, sisters take no share of the land at all. Again, how much a surviving
widow is given depends on circumstances. She may take a quarter of the estate;
or if, for example, she has enough land of her own to keep her, she may take
none. And I never heard of anyone in the village suggesting that a widower
would not be fully entitled to any land his wife might have owned, though
legally, like a widow he is only entitled to a quarter, (6) or the usufruct of half,



 




  if his wife's children survive her.

Most village divisions of inheritance would illustrate the point, and I will quote
only one, very briefly, and with some simplification. In the last generation,
Bilal, the head of one landowning household married the sister of his
neighbour, Suleyman, the head of another, but she took no land as her share of
her father's land. On Bilal's death, his only son, Ahmet, took over all the land;
and on Suleyman's death the land was divided between his three sons, Yakup,
Yusuf, and Zubeyr. Of these, Yakup and Yusuf married their kinswomen
(father's sister's daughters), the sisters of Ahmet. Much later these two agreed
with Ahmet to rearrange their land so as to give the women a share in the
inheritance. They were to give Ahmet their father's sister's share, and receive
their wives' shares from him. For all three households, the plan involved giving
up land, but each would receive in exchange at least the equivalent amount. But
the third brother, Zubeyr, whose wife was from a different family, would have
given land but received none. He refused to agree, and has quarrelled violently,
literally violently, with his brothers. Neither side wishes to go to law. Not only
would the inevitable complexity and slowness of court procedure involve the
litigants in much expense and inconvenience, but no one could be sure what the
court would decide, or how much readjustment of land might turn out to be
necessary. And so the matter rests, and like many, even in practice, disturbing
the existing non-legal though hardly illegal, distribution of the land.

This divergence between actual practice and the rules laid down by the law is
not in most cases the result of ignorance or of disapproval. I am not sure what
inheritance rules were practised in these villages before the introduction of the
code. Apart from a few informants whom I had reason to doubt, people
generally agreed that they had always divided inheritance equally between
children. Whether by this they meant sons only or sons and daughters, was not
clear. In practice sisters did sometimes take a share either in land or in cash. I
could, however, find no evidence that they were ever given shares amounting to
half that given to their brothers, though everyone in the villages knew that
according to Islamic law, they should have been.

According to Gibb and Bowen, (7) much land in the villages was, under the late
Ottoman Empire, theoretically State land in which the individual 'owners' held
rights of use, subject to a more or less fictional overriding 'ownership' by the
State. The State was thus able to lay down non-Islamic rules of inheritance,
since Islamic rules apply only to musk or full private property. Gibb and
Bowen state that holdings normally passed on the death of the
holder to his sons.(8)



 




  Existing village society is strongly agnatic, or patrilineal, that is, people
normally belong to groups to the members of which they are related in the male
line only. The villagers often speak as though areas of village land were owned
by these groups, that is, as though agnatically (patrilineally) related households
owned contiguous plots of land, as in fact they often do. This implies,
consistently with Gibb and Bowen, that brothers have normally shared land
among themselves and excluded their sisters.

My conclusion is that village inheritance rules have in the recent past not been
Islamic, but have been simple and flexible. Usually, land is divided between
brothers, but sometimes between brothers and sisters. Where landholding lines
died out, the land would normally revert to brothers, or, in some cases, appears
to have been taken over after a period by anyone needing it and having the man-
power and ox-power to work it.

This flexibility would explain why the villagers have accepted as equitable the
new rules of the Code, which are roughly consistent with one of the existing
village practices. I am confident they would not accept some of the details
which I never heard mentioned in the villages, for example, the limitation which
I have quoted above on the rights of a widower to his wife's land. But I did
hear the new inheritance laws discussed in general and heard no disapproval on
grounds either of religious unorthodoxy or of inequity.

But theoretical acceptance of what they know of the new laws does not lead
them to seek to apply the law when property owners die, still less to call in the
official institutions to ensure that the law is correctly carried out. Without here
entering upon a full discussion of village social structure I would like to suggest
three relevant sets of facts, two in connexion with social relations within the
village, and one with the relations between the village and the greater society,
which make their own flexible informal system preferable to the rigid system of
the Code and the courts.

First, when a landowner dies, the people most nearly involved are all on the
spot, living in his household, or at least in the same village or group of villages.
These people have a multiplicity of relationships and of formal and informal
rights and duties to each other. The readjustments which the removal of the
head of a kinship group requires are considerable, and it is better to take these
slowly, and work out the redistribution of property rights ad hoc, than to call in
officials who will ruthlessly apply the legally correct rules, and force all the
permanent and final rearrangements of ownership to be made at once. In fact,
the village, by taking the readjustments slowly, often postpones indefinitely the
'correct' redistribution of property, and creates vested interests which are
anxious to prevent this from ever happening. Hence neither at the time of the



 




  death, nor later, are the people concerned or anxious to register the changes of
property, or submit them to legal scrutiny. I do not know whether, in areas
where the land has recently been registered, people then proceed regularly to
register all changes of ownership, but my guess would be that in many cases
they do not.

Secondly, the law, though nominally acceptable, is not altogether in conformity
with the agnatic structure of village society. Whereas adult sons remain with
their father's household even after marriage, and work his land under his
direction until he dies, daughters marry out, and live and work in other
households. The brothers tend to regard the land which they have worked
together as theirs, and are unwilling to allow parts of it to pass to their sisters'
husbands' households. Moreover, the married sisters are not on the spot, and
are not, as the brothers are, in immediate need of the land of their dead father,
since they are supported by their husbands. Hence, as I have said, the brothers
frequently divide the land between themselves at the time of the death. It is left
to the sisters, sooner or later to upset this de facto arrangement, if they wish
to—and if they can enlist sufficiently powerful support. In many cases, sisters
and their husbands told me it would be disgraceful of them to stake a claim,
since their brothers had barely enough land anyway. The longer they wait, the
more difficult readjustment becomes.

But apart from the inherent rigidity of the legal rules, the proper application of
the law, especially where land is registered, means reference to officials, and
the approval of a judge, which brings me to the third point, a much more
general one. People living in rural communities all over the world are
suspicious of urban educated classes. Calling in lawyers and officials is
dangerous; not only does it mean expense and inconvenience, but one never
knows what they might discover, how they will use their knowledge, nor
whether they will even carry out their official acts in the way one had hoped and
expected. This point applies to far more than matters of inheritance—it applies
to marriage, for example, though I do not explicitly mention it in my discussion
of marriage below.

But not only do inheritance practices diverge from the formal law, even the sale
of land sometimes takes a traditional form not legally recognized. In several
cases, villagers claimed the return, at the original cash price, of a piece of land
they or their father had sold. Such claims were not only common, but generally
accepted; and land is still sold to raise immediate cash, for a price for which the
vendor intends later to recover it. Though my inquiries on the point are not
absolutely exhaustive, I am sure that no special documents or special oral
conditions of sale were quoted in stating the claims. No villager gives up land



Next Page   Contents

Return to Papers index