Previous Page




  receives all visitors, especially all officials. He passes on orders and
regulations, makes statistical returns, makes out the electoral roll, reports
crimes, conveys special requests, certifies the identity of people and the truth of
their statements for state marriage ceremonies, bank loans and so on, is
responsible for seeing that military conscripts answer the call, and for assisting
tax collectors. He is also responsible for collecting the village local tax and
administering village funds. In all these duties the council should advise and
assist him.

It might be thought that such an office would carry high rank, and being thus
desirable, be in the hands of the highest ranking men of the village. In practice,
this is not so. It seems likely that originally the muhtar was the leading villager,
and all the evidence indicates that, until the effect of the Ataturk revolution
reached the villages, it was so. The situation has changed. The office still gives
a man considerable power, which he is likely, to a greater or lesser extent, to
wield to his advantage, and makes many of his neighbours dependent on him.
Perhaps the most coveted privilege of the office is that of entertaining all
important guests. But in spite of this, the office carries little or no prestige, and
the holding of the office has little effect on the rank of the holder within the
village. Unless an election is imposed from above, the village men simply
decide among themselves who is to hold the office—often there is no
competition. The reasons for this paradox would themselves provide material
for a full article. Many of the muhtar's duties are regarded as irksome and
menial, and their importance is not understood. Many of them irritate his
neighbours, and force him to act as the agent of the hostile " they ". Few men
want to be muhtar, and those who do may want the office for the wrong
reasons. Very often it falls to a young man. There may sometimes be
competition to control the office —in two cases in other villages the choice of
muhtar was the occasion for a fight between hostile lineages—but none to hold
it. The muhtar in S during my stay was the son of a moderately well off old
man, and was aged about thirty, with low prestige on the moral-religious scale.
The council of elders does very little to check, advise or assist the muhtar. In
many villages, it seems never to meet, and the muhtar simply stamps all
documents with the seals of the members, which they give him for this
purpose. Membership of it carries little or no prestige or power.

The result of the divorce of the formal political scale from the other scales of
ranking in the village is that the village has no effective leadership at all. There
is no one who can initiate corporate action, no one who can resist effectively
anti-social activities, such as ploughing up common pasture land, no one who
has the necessary power and prestige to settle disputes within the village, or to
enforce traditional customs. The muhtar cannot rule the village because he has



 




  no prestige, the village elders, who have wealth and religious and moral
standing, cannot rule the village because they have no political power and no
backing from the government. The result tends to be stalemate. All that happens
happens by direct orders from above, which often fail to win any spontaneous
support from the village. As a result, very often the effectiveness of government
measures is lost or greatly diminished when they reach the village level. The
village, on the other hand, takes no initiative on its own behalf. I am not
maintaining that this is universally true, it applies in different degrees in
different villages—very little in some, especially the more or less suburban
ones—but it certainly applies to all the villages which I visited in the area in
which I worked, and some in other areas also.

If there is no effective political leadership, what do I mean by " public authority
" and " leadership " which I attribute to those who rank highest in the village? I
have mentioned many of the symbols of respect, such as forms of address,
station in the mosque, and positioning in the odalar. Prestige is open and easy
to observe. The use of power outside the formal hierarchy is not open, and
direct questioning often meets only with denial. The village leaders exercise a
minimum negative influence on public affairs, the choice of muhtar, important
decisions, and so on. When the village accounts were found to be
unsatisfactory at a change of muhtar, I found almost all the village leaders
gathered in the new muhtar's oda, although many of them would not normally
have darkened his door. Another large gathering assembled when the order to
prepare an electoral roll for the 1950 election reached the village. The village
leaders also have influence over a wide circle in such matters as marriage,
housing arrangements, sale of land, and so on, because their advice carries
weight, and in some cases their help may be a decisive factor. Another matter
decided by informal authority of this sort in S was the choice of the " imam " or
" hoja'',(5) who changes frequently. But for each leading figure, the circle of
influence was limited, and there was rivalry between them. It is, therefore,
justifiable to speak of the senior, religiously respected and better-off villagers as
leaders, and yet to say that there is no effective leadership for the village as a
whole.

This discussion of the effect on the village ranking system of the formal political
hierarchy is largely a digression, necessary in the context in order to establish a
negative reading. Aside, therefore, from this political scale, I have distinguished
three sets of scales of rank in the village; or to put it in the other vocabulary, I
have distinguished three groups of factors determining rank. These are age and
position in one's own family and lineage; wealth and occupation; and morality
and religion. There is no single scale of rank, but many scales which differ
slightly from each other. Every man would rank the village differently. One
might even say that each man has different scales for different contexts. The



 




  single composite scale of ranking to which we are committed, if we speak of "
factors determining rank ", does not, speaking strictly, exist at all. But the many
separate scales are so near each other as to justify the fiction of an overall scale,
so long as we recognise it as approximate and not fixed. The fact is that the
village, like all human groups, has leaders, men who rank high in all spheres.

The position of a man on the three scales is not equally within his own  control.
A man's age and his position in his own family and lineage are fixed for him.
His wealth, especially now that there is no spare land in S,. depends only to a
limited extent on his own efforts. To a large degree it is a matter of inheritance
and good fortune. On the other hand, the religious and moral conduct of a man
is his own choice. The interaction of the scales is limited by these facts. High
rank in a scale outside a man's control tends to make him behave so as to
maintain that rank in scales dependent on his own efforts.

It is a commonplace that the old become more pious. This is usually attributed
to fear of approaching death, and concern for welfare in the next world. I
suggest that to some extent and in some cases the piety of the aged may be an
attempt to live up to the higher rank in the community which their seniority
automatically brings them. In the same way, the better off in S were noticeably
more careful of the moral and customary norms than the poorer families.
Similarly, within the wealth scale, I found also that the majority of the skilled
migrant labourers from the village were not, as one might expect, the poorest
whose need was most, but that they usually came from households with a fair
amount of land, while the poor and landless households supplied unskilled
labour. On the other hand, obviously no other scale of rank can affect a man's
age, nor high rank on the religious-moral scale than a man's wealth.

A bad score, so to speak, on one scale, drags a man down in the overall scale.
Here again, the degree to which he is felt to be responsible makes a difference.
A poor man of senior years, and of high moral and religious rank is treated with
general respect, but a man of wealth and seniority of known unreliability may
receive little. Although wealth is the main source of public authority and power,
a bad reputation will destroy a man's power. On the other hand, high moral and
religious rank does not bring power of itself. All three, wealth, moral reputation
and seniority are necessary for a man to carry serious public influence.

I have attempted in this article to describe the system of ranking in the village I
studied in as abstract and formal terms as possible, but without any sacrifice of
accuracy or precision, and without introducing any concepts or theoretical
distinctions which did not seem to me to be absolutely necessary to my
purpose. For this reason, I have not given the ethnographic evidence, much of



 




  which can be found in my thesis on the village, and I have not made any attempt
to elaborate theoretically the concepts I have used. Since my aim has been
description, it seems legitimate to conclude without stating any conclusions.

NOTES

1 G. C. Homans, The Human Group, 1951.

2 Turkish, " buyukler ".

3 £T10 approximately equals £1 5s. od., or $3.50, at present exchange rates.

4 Turkish, " haci ".

5 Turkish,“ hoca ".

6 " The Social Structure of Turkish Peasant Communities," a dissertation
submitted at Oxford University in 1951.



   Contents

Return to Papers index