Previous Page


  17

  renting or sharecropping, thus releasing more male
labour to earn remittances in the towns.


From 1974 to 1984, I visited the village briefly many
times, and was able to observe that these processes
were continuing.  Households continued to leave;
young men to go off to work.  In 1973, the oil crisis
in Europe made it very difficult to get into Europe to
work, except with the help of close kin, or by risky
'tourist' adventures.  [Adadan Unat et al ed 197 ]
Instead, men already established there took their
village or urban Turkish households to Europe;
mostly to Germany.  In 1977 or thereabouts, some
men from S got themselves established, nearly all in
the building industry, in Saudi Arabia.  Saudi
regulations, it seems, required every foreign worker
not employed by a company to have a native Saudi
sponsor.  Sponsors had a lot of power, and exercised
it in different ways, some ruthlessly; the migrants
complained a lot about them.  People found sponsors
for their kin and friends, often charging quite large
fees for this service.  Most of the those who went
seemed to make very good money, but many
complained about their sponsors.  By 1981, I listed
100 men born in S working in Saudi Arabia, and in
1986, 150, of whom less than 50 were from urban
households.   By 1993, hardly any men of S were
still in Saudi Arabia, but a considerable number were
working in Russia, paid by Turkish companies in US
dollars.

In 1986, at least 80% of the 153 households in the
village had at least one member earning outside the
village.  Those that did not had no one to send, and
some of these had kin resident in the towns who
helped to provide for them.  

(ii).  Population

The total population of the village (Table 1) in 1950
was 636.  The households in Table 1 are those



 


  18

  descended patrilineally from those 636, including
incoming wives, but excluding daughters who
married out.  On this imprecise measure - and a few
people must have slipped through our research net -,
while the national population grew by slightly less
than 2.5 times, the village grew by almost three
times; the direct result of a falling death rate,
especially among very young children.  Such a
sudden change in the number of surviving children
has multiple consequences, not only for economic
viability, but also for kinship, for the structure and
fission of households, and for marriage
arrangements.  Marriage to cousins is common, and
when several siblings have eight or ten surviving
children each, the number of available cousins rises
sharply [Stirling 1995].

(iii).  Income

I have found it impossible to offer any index of the
rise in incomes, either of the households, or of the
village as a whole; still less of the migrant
descendents of the 1950 villagers.  This village,
indeed, this whole area, seems to have done a good
deal better than the national average, partly by luck.
I estimated above that the national product grew
about 8 times, and the total product per capita about
3 times between 1950 and 1986.  Such numbers mean
little in the village context, but it is possible to
describe the rise in the material standard of living,
and in the available resources.

In 1950, people went about in patched clothes, or in
rags; some women and children had no shoes to wear
in the winter snow.  Even the well to do households,
following a harvest failure, had extremely modest
diets; most of the poor were hungry and
malnourished by the time of the next harvest.  In the
winter of 1949-50, most households lived in one
room to save fuel, and a few only possessed one
room anyway.  Only nine households provided heat
for a `guest' room, misafir odas, in which nine



 


  19

  rooms all the men of the village assembled every
evening after a meal and prayers at sundown,
aksam,to gossip before the fifth and final prayer and
bed.  Every household head claimed to be in debt;
and I had good grounds to believe most of them.
[Stirling 1965, pp.44-98]

By 1986, virtually everyone in the village had plenty
to eat, and adequate clothes.  Virtually all households
had a television set, and most had refrigerators.
Most had at least one decent sitting room, and most
had at least two heated rooms in the winter; at any
rate, whenever it was socially desirable.  Men no
longer congregated in the evening, but sat at home,
or visited  as they wished; sometimes in mixed
company.  The village owned 26 tractors, a large
number of milk cows of European breeds,  and so
on.  What is much more significant, though
obviously everyone still complained about shortages
of cash for weddings, for investment in new housing
and so on, is many owned land or housing in the
towns.  Of course there were a few poor households,
but even these were not as poor as the poor majority
of 1950.  Of course, people borrowed for specific
purposes, and there were debts, some serious.  But
by and large, most operating costs of agriculture
were met by remittances, and no households faced
the grinding debts of 1950.  Not a rich community,
though one or two households were quite well-to-do.
One for example had built a busy petrol station just
on the village border,and owned and operated a large
petrol tanker to supply it.  The quality, availability
and affordability of medical services were
incomparably greater.  The village was several times
better off in material terms than in 1950.

This improvement was almost exclusively due to
remittances from migrants.  Agriculture had
changed, though the main structure was  similar.
With mechanisation - I photographed the last pair of
oxen in 1984 - , fertilisers, different crop patterns
and new varieties, and much more milk production,
overall production had perhaps doubled, at the cost



 


  20

  of investments and much higher operating costs.
And from around 1960, village girls had begun to
weave carpets commercially, more or less as wage
labour working in their own homes.  But these two
sources accounted for only a small part of the rise in
the standard of living.

Even in 1950, this village could not have survived
without income from its migrant labour, and the
most conspicuous consumption was the houses and
furnishings of the successful migrants.  But by 1986,
remittances were the main source of the community
income.  I cannot measure this; but I offer a guess,
based on questions asked and notes made on various
visits to the village.  Very roughly, in 1950, 80% of
total income was from agriculture, and 20% from
remittances.  In 1986, remittances may have been
about 60%, a more productive agriculture about
30%, and carpet weaving by women about 10%.
These figures ignore small percentages, for example,
kilims in 1950, and from investments and pensions in
1986.  

In this guess, I have of course ignored the urban
migrants.  A few who have suffered misfortune or
who cannot find or do well paid work are poor,
struggling to feed the household in low grade  rented
housing.  Most are at least moderately successful, and
own their own town houses.  Many are well off,
owning real estate, and running small businesses.
Three or four are wealthy; one runs one of the
largest building firms in Adana.  Some of these
successful people keep close ties with village
households, supporting the elderly or unfortunate,
helping with special needs like weddings, or co-
operating in investment projects.  Several groups of
siblings co-operate in this way, sometimes with their
father or a brother in the village.  Very recently
(1993), three of four households with adequate land
holdings and elderly heads have moved to town, and
now derive a part of their urban income from their
their village land.  



Next Page   Contents

Return to Papers index